Why The Fed, by itself, cannot deliver a sustainable recovery?
Part 3 : food for thought
2.3
What should the Fed worry about now?
· Life after QE: The Fed’s
QE program had different goals and outcomes all along.
The successful QE1,
which bought about $1.7 trillion worth of mortgage-backed securities and
Treasury bonds between Nov 2008 and March 2010, helped banks as house prices started
to crawl back from the depths of the recession.
By comparison, QE2, a
$600 billion program which lasted until June 2011, targeted to lower long-term interest
rates, with a view to “promote a stronger
pace of economic recovery”. This one was
viewed as failing to meet its objective.
QE3, which was
announced in September 2012, was a lot more audacious and targeted: having
observed the tight correlation between the size of QE and stock market
appreciation it was going to bet boldly in that direction. By levitating the
values of financial assets while spending a monthly $85 billion for an
open-ended period, it was banking on the “wealth effect” of investors to serve as
a catalyst for economic growth and job creation. Two years and over $1.8 trillion
later, the results are in: the stock market climbed another 40% in that period
but the “trickle-down” economics experiment failed. The recovery is still
tentative and more QE could have precarious and unintended consequences,
including speculative extremes.
The question now is what other kind of unconventional monetary
tools the Fed can employ if and when the economy relapses again: more QE is
clearly not the answer and relying on forward guidance (“talkware” as I call
it) does not look overly promising.
·
Size of its balance sheet: The Fed’s balance sheet had almost quintupled to over $4.5
trillion in assets in Q3 2014 when compared to its pre-recession size of seven
years ago. The financial press continues to suggest that, should interest rates
rise faster than anticipated, the Fed – which now controls assets 80 times
larger than its own equity capital – cannot completely ignore the risk posed by
such unprecedented leverage. Just a mere 1.5% drop in the value of its bonds
would wipe-out the capital on its books.
Although the Fed is better equipped than anyone to deal with the
technicalities of potential balance sheet impairment, it would undoubtedly be
at the expense of public confidence, the most valuable asset it has. So the
question of how to gracefully unwind or shrink that balance sheet cannot be
ignored, even when considering that, at 20% of nominal GDP, its scale is
comparable to the ones used by most central banks in Europe or the U.K. That
being said, it is noteworthy that the only time the Fed’s balance sheet
attained financial leverage close to this proportion was during the Great
Depression.
The issue finally boils down to whether any central bank can
indefinitely suppress interest rates in a “market-based” economy. If unlikely,
then how to shrink that balance sheet becomes not an option but a strategic
choice to be made as part of a master plan.
·
Monetary velocity: This measures the force with which money is put to work in the
economy and is a key metric the Fed relies on to gauge inflation. According to
recent research published by the St. Louis Fed, the velocity index was hovering
around 4.4 for most of 2014, significantly below the 17.2 measured just prior
to the recession. The inference here is that the private sector is holding more
cash, or hoarding money, instead of spending it either for consumer consumption
or industrial investments.
Households alone are reported to be sitting on well over $2
trillion in savings - about 50% higher than five years ago, despite negligibly
low interest rates on their deposits. This implies that far more people than
before have chosen cash over interest-bearing assets such as government bonds
-- let alone equities -- from a risk/reward perspective. Increased thrift is an
undesirable drag to the credit-multiplier-effect that the Fed wants; but,
overheating asset prices made more savers hold cash despite repressive interest
rates encouraging to do just the opposite.
·
Soaring stock markets: QE1
alone was behind the first 70%
appreciation in the S&P 500 index which went on to triple in value between
March ’09 and August ’14. In about 5.5 years the S&P has indeed climbed
from 700 to 2000 as a majority of yield-starved investors embraced both stocks
-- and bonds -- as the least bad of all alternatives.
But it would be a
mistake to think of the stock market as a “leading indicator” of economic
recovery. It is indeed that misplaced sense of confidence in the inflated value
of stocks which preceded the crashes of 2001 and 2008. No, increased investor
wealth does not easily translate into more jobs and rising incomes– both
largely considered as indispensable for economic growth in a consumption
society like the US. The “trickle-down” theory of supply-side economics is
again proving to be unreliable at best.
What looks more
certain however is that the next recession, most likely associated with a
severe stock market contraction, will be attributed to the prolonged period the
Fed maintained its ZIRP and QE policies. Artificially low interest rates have a
history of conditioning investor psychology to overlook the inherent risks with
capital allocation: how can the Fed forget that cheap credit, maintained for a
period longer than necessary, was directly linked with the real-estate bubble
that led to the Great Recession of 2008?
· Adverse global cross-currents: To-date only the US, Japan and the UK have chosen QE to flatten
the yield curve -- or overtly control long-term interest rates-- through the
massive swapping of cash with tradable bonds. The ECB has stayed clearly
behind, up until now.
But, as the US starts
withdrawing QE while Japan continues to expand its own program, we have already
witnessed abrupt exchange-rate dislocations -- harbingers of disruptive capital
flows and potential trade conflicts. If and when the EU decides to embrace QE,
because it is out-of-synch with the US, it will cause a similar except much
larger instability in exchange rates and capital movements. The impact on the
US of such instability is not clear yet.
Stalling, if not reversing of the potential US recovery with external
forces capable of enlarging the trade deficit and adding to deflationary risks
(coming from lower import prices) should be a concern for all American economic
policymakers, including the Fed.
No comments:
Post a Comment