Why The Fed, by itself, cannot deliver a sustainable recovery?
Part 5 - The Impasse
3.0 THE IMPASSE
3.1 The nature of the problem
Now that QE3 is concluded at the end of October 2014, the Fed
now finds itself in one of the least desirable situations in its history
because of:
a) An oversized balance
sheet precluding further large bond purchases anytime soon;
b)
Interest rates
sitting at unprecedented lows with not much room for further easing;
c)
Inflated financial
asset prices whose contraction threatens any hope of stability;
d)
The US$ rising
against other currencies fueling the risk of even larger trade deficits;
e)
Reduced capabilities
in its so-called “toolbox” to fight the next financial crisis.
Simply put, the Fed
is at a cul-de-sac: after six years of repressively low interest rates --
bolstered by a bloated balance sheet comprising $4.5 T in assets -- the
abnormally fragile recovery points to the need to question some of its
fundamental economic beliefs. Chief among them is that an expansionary monetary
policy – abundant and cheap credit – is the most critical requirement of
renewed economic growth and prosperity. Is
it really ?
In previous
recessions economic recoveries had been faster to arrive – without QE – and
more robust. This time around, yes, we did avoid a full-scale financial panic,
but we are still lacking any proof that monetary policy since 2008 has
delivered sustainable growth.
Take the employment
scene. Although the unemployment rate has declined measurably, stubbornly
stagnant wage-growth across a majority of industries is seriously undermining
household consumption from reaching the levels needed for a true economic
rebound.
Take business
investments. The conspicuous absence of large corporate investments to bolster
job creation nationwide casts considerable doubt on the assumptions underlying
the Fed’s monetary policies. Yes, low-interest rates have facilitated debt
rescheduling and stock buybacks for most large corporations – manifestly benefiting
shareholders and no one else in the strictest economic sense – but there is
scant evidence that the investment climate for new job creation has improved.
If anything, we are witnessing some of the largest corporations threatening to
leave the USA in search of preferential tax treatments elsewhere at the expense
of domestic employment. (i.e. the highly controversial tax inversion
initiatives). It is now clear that those jobs-friendly investment expectations
were misplaced.
All of that points to
the accepted wisdom in political science which holds a multitude of government
policies – not just monetary policy – responsible for economic growth. Monetary
policy, without complementary fiscal and trade policies conceived to stimulate the
other three supporting pillars -- especially business investment, domestic
employment and consumer spending -- doesn’t go very far.
3.2 What if the Fed’s mandate was part of the problem?
Monetary policy in the US has over the last four
decades focused primarily on controlling money supply in order to carry out its
dual mandate of maintaining price stability and promoting maximum employment. But,
in an interconnected and more complex world of global finance, is maintaining
domestic price stability enough?
That
dual mandate was granted by Congress in 1977 when runaway inflation was a major
political and social concern. By focusing primarily on price stability, the
goal was to bring inflation under control in a way to provide broader financial
stability which is essential for capital investment and job creation. That
operation succeeded for a while.
However, since Fed chair Volcker’s
very effective use of high interest rates to combat double-digit inflation in
the 1980’s, financial stability has been regretfully equated by politicians, and
most financial pundits and academics, with simple price stability described as
the “taming” of inflation.The problem is that the low inflation attributed to
price stability is a necessary step in attaining financial stability, but it is
not sufficient.
There is a lot more
to financial stability than subdued inflation in a developed country whose
money serves as a global reserve currency. Chief among them is steadiness in
the value of its currency. And not too far from it is the predictability in the
frequency and severity of shocks that its economy experiences. Measured against
both of these criteria, the US monetary policy has badly failed to deliver
financial stability.
The US dollar has
been in steady decline relative to most other major currencies over the last 15
years -- by well over 40 % against the Euro until recently -- despite the Great
Recession. As to shocks or convulsions, we had two major ones in the last
decade: the Tech Bust of 2001 and the Great Subprime Crisis of 2007, both of
which have been attributed to the loose credit policies of a still mystifying “
we are high-flying, but watch us do a soft landing” mindset of
former Fed chairman, Alan Greenspan.
But is the real
problem the Fed’s performance or the misplaced expectations from its outdated
mandate? Should the mandate for the Fed – the central bank behind world’s
reserve currency – be reworked to include broader financial stability,
especially better and more dependable ways to predict and avoid severe shocks
to the financial system?
Japan, with a lot
more experience with ZIRP and QE since their dreadful asset-bubble burst 22
years ago, serves as a great example as to economic growth in need of a lot more than subdued inflation. Price
stability for an economy mired in structural stagnation is not sufficient. “Growth requires a lot more than monetary
policy”, admitted its former central bank Governor Shirakawa in a speech he
gave in London back in January 2012 “QE
just buys valuable time for mandatory structural changes and nothing else.”
he declared, while stressing that loose monetary policy without reforms is not
the answer.
Other countries can
also provide valuable insights regarding the role and expectations from a
central bank. Canada and Israel for instance have experience with mandating
higher down-payment requirements – instead of jacking-up interest rates – to
deflate speculative real-estate bubbles. Such “macro prudential” curbs, as they
are called, are part of the unconventional tools and powers that central banks
use for financial stability.
The U.K. serves also as a good example of foresight by explicitly adding the financial stability mandate to the mission of its central bank, the Bank of England, with the Financial Services Act of 2012.
It seems the new
vice-chair of the Fed, Stanley Fischer, is particularly attuned to the needs of
reworking the Fed’s mandate. By suggesting that Congress should consider making
financial stability an explicit mandate for all U.S. financial regulators, he
is pointing out the biggest need for change in American monetary policy: a
mandate which should go beyond the management of credit and inflation to also
include responsibility for financial stability. Otherwise, Alan Greenspan’s
suggestion of the inherent “inevitability” of boom and bust cycles in monetary
policy is missing an important yet overlooked aspect: accountability.
No comments:
Post a Comment